Ostrum
  • News & Chronicles
  • France
  • Euro Area
  • United States
  • International
  • Politics & Society
  • Monetary Policy
  • Media
  • Decoding
  • About Philippe Waechter
Philippe Waechter's blog
  • Insights
  • About us
  • Expertise
  • Our people
  • Media

Philippe Waechter's blog
My french blog
  • News & Chronicles
  • France
  • Euro Area
  • United States
  • International
  • Politics & Society
  • Monetary Policy
  • Media
  • Decoding
  • About Philippe Waechter
  • News & Chronicles
  • Climate
  • France
  • Euro Area
  • United States
  • International
  • Politics & Society
  • Monetary Policy
  • Media
  • Decoding
Philippe Waechter's blog
Prévôté
Previous
  • 4 min

Public debt – Private debt: the real heart of the matter is not where we think (Part 2)

  • 29 August 2017
  • Philippe Waechter
  • Private Debt
Total
0
Shares
0
0
0

In last week’s column (see here), I discussed the importance of public debt as an asset that enables wealth to be transferred to a date in the future, while restricting risk, along with its ability to effectively absorb economic shocks. I also noted that I was less concerned about public debt than private debt, particularly household debt.
The major difference between public debt and household debt is that a credible State issuer can issue debt with sometimes very long maturities, which households cannot do, so they do not have the same flexibility to adapt to shocks.
The other key point is that a State enjoys the advantage of being able to raise taxes, and this option of being able to potentially increase tax is reflected in investors’ confidence in sovereign issuers on the financial markets. When a State is seen as being unable to raise taxes, then its credit collapses and its ability to issue securities disappears. On developed markets, we can observe that the likelihood of a crisis related to public debt is therefore low.
However, it is a different kettle of fish for households, for two reasons. The first is that a household exists for a finite period of time and it cannot carry over its debt the way a State does. Public debt is never paid down, while household debt has to be paid off at some point.
The other difference is that the accumulation of household debt is based on the acquisition of an asset, usually a real estate property. The household’s ability to increase its debt is based on this asset’s capacity (which the debt is financing) to satisfactorily maintain its value. During the subprime crisis, we saw that this mechanism can grind to a halt when real estate property loses value.
In the event of a crisis, the only solution is to liquidate the asset, which triggers a watershed.
This is where the State played a key role after the subprime crisis, injecting public debt in order to absorb the shock and taking over from private debt, which could no longer be issued.
I mention the household debt issue for two reasons.
The first is that this type of debt increased considerably in the first decade of this century. Workers’ weak income growth was partly offset by the option of resorting to greater debt. Household debt can also be a reflection of an economic system that is no longer operating efficiently and we see this situation in the US and elsewhere.
The chart below shows the example of the US, with household debt rates on the horizontal axis and consumer spending as a percentage of GDP on the vertical axis.
us-2017-q1-conso-debt
We can identify several phases. In the 1960s, 1970s and up to the middle of the 1980s, there was no relationship between consumer spending and debt, but this situation changed during the mid-1980s as households took on debt in order to spend more. In the 2000s, they then took on debt to be able to continue spending in the same way. Debt has fallen since the financial crisis, consumer spending as a percentage of GDP has stabilized but growth in household spending is much slower than during previous economic cycles, as shown by the second chart.
usa-2017-q2-consumption-cycle comp
Excessive household debt then leads to a decrease in consumer spending against a backdrop where income is not increasing quickly (problem of insufficient productivity gains but this is not specific to America).
This relationship between debt and consumer spending emerged at the same time as the imbalance in income distribution materialized in the US, as greater divergences appeared in the distribution of income. In the 1960s and 1970s, productivity gains drove wage income, then in the mid-1980s, median wages began to grow much more slowly and households were forced to get into debt to maintain their spending. This trend is not very efficient in the long term, as shown by the current situation.
The other reason is that household debt underpinned the surge in the real estate market before the crisis in 2007/2008. The accumulation in debt had led to an increase in real estate prices, which turned out to be unsustainable in the medium term. The problem today is that household debt has not really decreased in the euro area and it is rising swiftly in the UK due to both the increase in nominal debt and also the fast drop in disposable income. Meanwhile, in the US, household debt is down.
Generally speaking, households’ high debt restricts their leeway to adapt as income momentum remains limited across the board. It is therefore important and necessary to generate substantial productivity gains to be able to distribute sufficient income to limit household debt overall.
hhdebt-comp-2017-q1-uk-us-ea
Household debt reflects households’ ability to increase their resources via the acquisition of a durable good, but when this amassing of debt is not built on a well-valued underlying asset, then economic momentum is hampered. This is when public debt can take over to help smooth out adjustments over time and thereby avoid drastic shifts that dent both jobs and income.
This is the translated version of my weekly column for Forbes. You can read it here in French

Related Topics
  • Private Debt
Subscribe to the newsletter

All the news from Philippe Waechter’s blog in your mailbox


Loading

Le magazine d’experts d’Ostrum

ABOUT OSTRUM AM
  • About us
  • Media room
  • Our publications
  • Cookie Policy (EU)
FOLLOW ME ON
EXTERNAL LINKS
  • Economists
  • Think tank
  • Central banks
  • Blog roll
©Ostrum AM 2025
An affiliate of : Plan de travail 2

Input your search keywords and press Enter.

Manage Cookie Consent
We use cookies to optimize our website and our service.
Functional Always active
The technical storage or access is strictly necessary for the legitimate purpose of enabling the use of a specific service explicitly requested by the subscriber or user, or for the sole purpose of carrying out the transmission of a communication over an electronic communications network.
Preferences
The technical storage or access is necessary for the legitimate purpose of storing preferences that are not requested by the subscriber or user.
Statistics
The technical storage or access that is used exclusively for statistical purposes. The technical storage or access that is used exclusively for anonymous statistical purposes. Without a subpoena, voluntary compliance on the part of your Internet Service Provider, or additional records from a third party, information stored or retrieved for this purpose alone cannot usually be used to identify you.
Marketing
The technical storage or access is required to create user profiles to send advertising, or to track the user on a website or across several websites for similar marketing purposes.
Manage options Manage services Manage {vendor_count} vendors Read more about these purposes
View preferences
{title} {title} {title}